THE IMPACT OF BANKING REGULATION ON THE EMERGENCE OF CRISES IN EMERGING COUNTRIES

Rim Mekki

Higher Institute of Management of Sousse, University of Sousse, Tunisia

ABSTRACT

In this study, we analyzed the regulatory, macroeconomic and institutional environmental effects on the probability of the emergence of banking crises in 78 emerging countries that had a fragile banking system in 1997 in a cross-sectional study using a logit model. The empirical examination validates a link between the weakness of certain regulatory and macroeconomic factors and of newly liberalized emerging market banking crises, this study want to examine weakness of regulatory and macroeconomic factors of newly liberalized, etc. banking concentration, restrictions on insurance, the financial market and the real estate sector were not related to the outbreak of banking crises in our estimates. On the basis of results, this study concludes that good regulation leads to bank stability. However, certain restrictions on inappropriate banking activity were the causes of the emergence of banking crises. As a result, the fragility of macroeconomic and institutional factors and the lack of diversification has clearly led to bank fragility and consequently to banking crises.

Keywords: Financial liberalization, Emerging countries, Banking crisis, Bank regulation, Logit, Financial fragility.

ARTICLE HISTORY: Received:14 May 2019 Revised:17 June 2019 Accepted:19 July 2019 Published:7 August 2019.

Contribution/ Originality:This study contributes to the existing literature by considering that the vulnerability of banks in emerging countries reflects a fragile and inefficient banking system. Thus a strong restriction of certain banking activities accompanied by a deterioration of the macroeconomic factors and a weakness of some institutional factors can lead to banking crises.

1. INTRODUCTION

The literature on financial liberalization and its effects on the economies of countries gives mixed opinions. Few studies conclude that liberalization strengthens financial development and contributes to long-term growth  (Tanna et al., 2017; Rachdi et al., 2018). Other studies focused on the negative effects on financial stability and the succession of banking crises over the decades (Rancière and Tornell, 2016; Gnangnon, 2018; Ambrogio et al., 2019) . Several reasons account for this discrepancy.

Keeley (1990); Hellmann et al. (2000) and Repullo (2004) explained the negative influence of financial liberalization through banking competition 1. Others insisted that financial liberalization could affect the stability through different channels outside of changes and competition from banks (for example, by encouraging bank risk-taking, by broadening the possibilities of taking risks in the foreign market or in non-traditional activities) (Cubillas and González 2014).Thus, even if the competitive incentives for banks to take risks do not change, banks could take more risks by participating in new activities (Barth et al., 2004).

Overall, the literature on the effect of financial liberalization on the emergence of banking crises fails to reach a concrete conclusion. For example, Joyce (2011) stated that countries with more open capital regimes are less likely to have bank crises and that these crises were more likely to occur when a country has a current account deficit. Schaeck et al. (2009); Angkinand et al. (2010); Allen et al. (2011); Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (1999) found that macroeconomic factors such as GDP growth, interest rates, inflation, and capital flows have an impact on the emergence of banking crises. However, the banking crises were also explained by poor or weak banking regulation according to Cubillas and Suárez (2018). The work of Barth et al. (2004;2008) found that the more countries intensified banking regulation and supervision, the more crises were expected to increase.

This literature review reveals the absence of any studies that have looked at all of the following aspects: macroeconomic, institutional, regulatory and more specifically, restrictions on certain sectors to explain crises. Different studies have always focused on one of these aspects to explain banking crises. There is a real need to analyze the effect of all these aspects on the triggering of banking crises in emerging countries. The objective of this article is to fill this gap and to analyze the impact of macroeconomic, institutional and regulatory factors in triggering banking crises.

Our results suggested that restrictive monetary policies that keep macroeconomic and institutional variables under control were advantageous when it comes to banking sector stability. However, we found that banks’ risk-taking was not well accompanied by good banking regulation. Indeed, imposing a lot of restrictions on certain sectors has limited the diversification of banks' revenues which led eventually to crises. The outline of the elements of banking supervision is in Section 2 of this paper, Section 3 discusses the role of institutional factors in the form of compliance and corruption, a presentation of the data and indicators used to measure banking crisis is presented in Section 4, an interpretation of the results is in Section 5 and the last section is devoted to the conclusion.

2. THE ROLE OF BANKING SECTOR SUPERVISION IN BANKING CRISES

Regulation or banking supervision includes all standards aimed at supporting the soundness of credit institutions. The main objectives of regulation are to reduce risks for banks, investors and investments, as well as to ensure transparency between credit institutions and depositors. In this section we will present a synthesis of the existing literature on the different types of banking regulations.

2.1. Supervision of the Banking Sector

The fundamental role of banking supervision is to ensure banking stability by minimizing risks to banks. For the early 2000s, Barth et al. (2004) noted that increased activity restrictions on banks led these institutions to take more risks. Similarly, Zhang et al. (2016) examined the behavior of banks in China following the reduction in the high level of non-performing loans by Chinese banking authorities. In order to achieve this result, the authors used a panel regression model and data covering 60 urban commercial banks, sixteen public banks and eleven rural commercial banks over the period from 2006 to 2012. They found that an increase in the non-performing loan ratio increased the number of riskiest loans, which could lead to deterioration in loan quality and instability in the financial system.

2.2. Bank Concentration

Banks that borrow more money from other banks tend to have fewer and more concentrated deposit-taking relationships. Large banks and banks in areas where there are more potential customers tend to establish more numerous and diversified interbank relationships. However, the concentration-fragility relationship presented by several authors such as Boyd and Nicolo (2005); Schaeck et al. (2009) and Allen et al. (2011) suggested that large banks in a concentrated market weaken its stability.

Contrary to this research, Khan et al. (2016) studied financial stability in several Southeast Asian economies (Malaysia, Indonesia, Singapore, Philippines and Thailand) between 1995 and 2014 and found that the relationship between concentration and competition from banks played an important role not only in the efficiency of banks but also in the stability of the financial system, economic growth, the transmission of monetary policy and access to credit.

2.3. Regulation of the Right of Entry of Foreign Banks into the Local Market

The number of foreign banks has increased significantly in emerging Asian and Latin American countries since the early 1990s. Banking markets in these economies have become increasingly international due to financial liberalization, widespread privatization, financial integration and banking reform efforts. The impact of this increasing entry of foreign banks on the competitive structure of domestic banking markets has been widely debated.

Onder and Ozyilidirim (2019) found that the presence of foreign banks in Latin America over the period between 1999 and 2011 was negatively and significantly correlated with macroeconomic volatility both in normal times and in periods of crisis.

A contradictory study was presented by Wu et al. (2017). They used banking panel data on Asia and Latin America during the period from 1997 to 2008 to show that an increase in the penetration of foreign banks improved competition in the banks of these host countries and strengthened their banking systems.

2.4. Deposit Insurance

Deposit insurance is widely available in a number of countries as part of a financial system safety net to promote stability. However, it appears to have an unanticipated effect. Deposit insurance reduces the incentive for depositors to monitor banks and risk-taking tends to increase. In the following section, we examine the effect of deposit insurance on bank fragility.

In addition, Anginer et al. (2014) found that good banking supervision can mitigate the unintended consequences of deposit insurance on systemic banking risk. They predicted that if institutions were good, moral hazard possibilities were more limited. Effective prudential regulation and supervision could compensate for the negative incentives created by deposit insurance. In other words, the impact of deposit insurance on bank stability tended to be stronger when the system was managed by the government rather than by the private sector.

Egan et al. (2017) developed a quantitative model of the US banking sector through new data and covering the largest US banks over the period from 2002 to 2013. The model included insured depositors and uninsured depositors. The results showed that increasing deposit insurance coverage could increase or decrease the risk to financial stability depending on whether banks or depositors benefited from the increase in insurance. The estimated demand for uninsured deposits decreased with the financial distress of banks. Egan et al. (2017) also found that a capital requirement of less than 18% could result in a significant instability in the banking system.

If financial liberalization and the fragility of banking supervision are considered to be factors that triggered bank crises, then are they also relevant for institutional factors?

3. ROLE OF INSTITUTIONS ON THE APPEARANCE OF CRISES

Legal institutions in the form of law and rules of law as well as economic institutions as a system of supervision and regulation of banks form the main determinants of financial development. The law and the rules of law are two theories that explain financial development.

The theory of law and finance is derived from the legal system and has an effect on financial development. Each country has its own right to protect private property as well as protection according to the different institutions. Indeed, weak institutions have been placed in regions hostile to colonizers, so that the exploitation of the resources of these countries is quick and easy, resulting in a lack of protection of private property rights and weak support for financial development

3.1. The Law

The theory of law and finance was derived from the legal system and has an effect on financial development. Each country has its own right to be adapted to protect private property as well as all protection corresponding to the different institutions. La Porta et al. (1997;1998) were the founders of this theory.

The basic foundation of this theory is the role of legal institutions in financial development. As a result, countries that have a legal system that facilitates contracts between private agents and protects their rights and those of investors will be encouraged to invest in companies. When investors feel secure, they will be able to contribute to the development of the financial market. In contrast, if a country is managed by a legal system that did not protect property rights and investors, its financial development would slow down.

3.2. Corruption

The absence of corruption or, more specifically, transparency between banks and their depositors can be seen as an institutional factor that can affect the occurrence of banking crises. As a result, opinions are mixed on this factor. As Park (2012) examined the impact of corruption on the banking system and economic growth using a sample of 70 cross-sectioned countries from 2002 to2004. His main conclusion was that corruption increased risky loans. Consequently, it is the main cause of the onset of financial crises and the deterioration of growth.

In studying the impact of the legal and institutional environment on the system of governance, La Porta et al. (2000) found a significant impact between investors and managers if there was a good environment for applying governance mechanisms. Similarly, Klapper and Love (2004) tested the impact of the regulatory and institutional environment on governance mechanisms in fourteen emerging countries. They found that weak governance existed in a weak regulatory and institutional environment.

4. EMPIRICAL STUDY

Substituting Equation 1 leads to 

Using CRISES, the variable to be explained indicating whether or not there is an outbreak of crises and i represents each country in the sample. A detailed description of the variables selected for our econometric study will be presented below.

4.1. Presentation of Data

To analyze the determinants of banking crises, the variables selected were related to macroeconomic, institutional and supervisory indicators and banking regulations. Our study covered a sample of 78 developing countries (see Table A1 in the Appendix), in 1997, the crisis-triggering period for the majority of emerging countries.

Our choice of explanatory variables reflects both the theory of the determinants of banking crises summarized in the previous sections and the availability of data.
The construction of the fictitious bank crisis variable was a key element of our study. In order to achieve these results, we identified and dated episodes of distress in the banking sector during 1997 using mainly the database of Laeven and Valencia (2013).

4.1.1. Bank Macroeconomic Indicators

We increased the share of non-performing loans that are disadvantageous to banks, to capture adverse macroeconomic shocks. We used real GDP growth rates as the explanatory variable. Ang and McKibbin (2007) argued that the variable that best reflected the progression of financial liberalization was the ratio of credit to the private sector to GDP so we considered this variable as an indicator of banking development and introduced it as regressed in our equations.

Inflation was introduced as an explanatory variable because it was likely to be associated with high nominal interest rates. We introduced the M2 ratio to foreign exchange reserves to check whether the problems of the banking sector were linked to sudden outflows of capital. According to Calvo (1996) this ratio was a good indicator of a country’s vulnerability to balance of payments crises. Banks are the main financial institutions of each country so the more the banking sector is developed, the higher the domestic credit so this variable was used to assess the credit boom.

4.1.2. Institutional Indicators

Regarding institutional variables, we chose two variables: the role of the law and corruption control. The role of law is an indicator that reflects the quality of contract execution. The corruption control variable is a variable that indicates transparency, in which public power is exercised for private purposes, including small and large forms of corruption. These two variables were taken from the World Bank. (The database of World Bank).

We mainly measured bank risk using the Z-score2 of banks. This variable measures distance from insolvency (Roy, 1952). It is an indicator of bank stability.

4.1.3. Indicators of Supervision and Banking Regulations

The level of competition in banking markets is a factor that affects risk taking. Therefore, we controlled the concentration of the five major banks at the level of industry and the country. In fact, the concentration rate was an indicator of the structure of the banking markets. In terms of banking regulation, we controlled the existence of a deposit insurance system. It was1 if the country used deposit insurance and 0 if not. Deposit insurance was an equally important variable in the institutional environment and can create incentives to take excessive risks (Kane, 1986). Therefore, we used the variables that measured the intensity and scope of regulation in the banking sector and on a national level, as defined in the global database on banking regulation in Barth et al. (2004). In addition, we used the level of capital stringency, the level of supervisory power of official banks, and business restrictions (Barth et al., 2004).

Business restrictions are indices measuring the regulatory limits imposed on banks operating in securities markets, insurance activities, real estate and the ownership of non-financial enterprises. In the selection of data on the regulation set out by Barth et al. (2004) we analyzed the rules that the theory evidences with regard to the behavior of banks. Hence, we were looking at capital regulation and regulatory restrictions on the emergence of banking crises. Capital was the regulatory oversight factor for Barth et al. (2004). It gave us insights of whether the source of funds that constitute regulatory capital might have included assets other than liquidity, government securities or borrowed funds. Capital included information on the extent of regulatory requirements regarding the amount of capital banks must hold.

Restriction represented the regulatory restrictions we have constructed from the survey of the banks activities of the Barth et al. (2004). It measured regulatory barriers for banks such as:

The values that we provided for securities, insurance and real estate ranged from 1 to 4, where higher values indicated more restrictions on banks operating each activity. In particular, 4 meant prohibited, 3 meant that there were strict restrictions on the provision of the activity, 2 meant that the activity was permitted but with certain limitations, and 1 indicated that the activity was permitted.

Regulatory index for the acquisition of non-bank firms: This index measured a bank’s ability to own the shares of a non-financial corporation and thus to diversify its sources of income. This index used a value of 1 to 4, if the rate was high it was a strong restriction, if it was low it was considered a small restriction. Table 1 summarizes the various variables selected, their definitions and their sources.

Table-1. The explanatory  variables.
Variables codes Variables Source
Growth GDP Growth annual % World Bank
Inflation Inflation GDP deflator annual % World Bank
Crédit Credit provided for the private sector as a percentage of GDP. World Bank
M2_reserve M2 ratio to foreign exchange reserves World Bank
Debdt Doubtful debts World Bank
Non-financial firms restrictiveness of ownership by nonfinancial firms of banks Barth et al. (2004)
Z_score Banking risk measurement BankScope
Rule of low Index that measures compliance with contracts World Bank
Corruption Measuring the transparency of banks World Bank
Concentration the 5-bank concentration ratio Barth et al. (2004)
Insurance Deposit insurance Beck et al. (2008)
Losses/loan Market value of loan losses Barth et al. (2004)
Losses/exchange Unrealized foreign exchange losses Barth et al. (2004)
Nb of   foreign applications Number of foreign applications for banking licenses Barth et al. (2004)
Nb of domestic applications Number of domestic applications for banking licenses Barth et al. (2004)

5. PRESENTATION OF THE RESULTS

As stated previously, we analyzed 78 emerging countries in order to determine the most significant variables that best explained the outbreak of banking crises. Table 2 presents the results of the estimates. We estimated three different specifications. In the first specification, we only used the macroeconomic variables specification (1) in Table 2. We added two variables (low and corruption) to the first specification to get the second specification (2) in Table 2. The last specification presented the full model with all variables including macroeconomic, institution and regulatory variables specification (3) in Table 2

The variable measuring growth was not significant according to the first specification. Given all variables in the first specification were not significant, we focused more on the second and the third specifications in our interpretation of the results. According the third specification in Table 2, the credit variable coefficient was positive, and strongly significant at the 1% significance level, which supported the argument that credit expansion signals bank fragility and an increase in crises.

The inflation variable had a significant coefficient. This confirmed the well-known vulnerability of the banking system to credit and inflation shocks. Thus, it appeared that weak GDP growth, high real interest rates and high inflation ere significantly correlated to the onset of a banking crisis. The M2 ratio to the central bank’s foreign exchange reserves, measuring external vulnerability to capital outflows, had a significant impact.

The variable measuring credit to the private sector and measuring banking development had a significant and positive effect. It appears that countries where the banking sector has greater exposure to private sector borrowers are more vulnerable to banking crises. This leads to confirming Abbas et al. (2017) results. With respect to institutional variables, our results showed that the law variable had a significantly negative effect for different types of countries. This showed that crises have arisen in countries that did not respect the law. This confirmed the work of Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (1999) which found that market discipline was stronger in countries with a higher level of institutional development, such as bureaucratic quality, bureaucratic delays, lack of corruption, quality of contracts and legal effectiveness However, they also found that even in countries where institutional development was strong, market discipline could be restricted by deposit insurance schemes that sand high limits, extend coverage to interbank deposits, and establish a permanent reserve fund.

However, the variable measuring corruption did not have a significant coefficient. This was contradictory to the work of Park (2012)who found that corruption increased bad debts and slowed down economic growth.

Table-2. Results of estimates.

Variables
Specification (1)
Specification (2)
Specification (3)
Growth
0,034
0,111
0,117
(0,089)
(0,127)
(0,095)
Inflation
0,004
0,003
0,005**
(0,006)
(0,004)
(0,002)
Credit
0,014
0,0371*
0,053***
(0,010)
(0,019)
(0,018)
M2_reserve
-0,189
-0,212
-0,288*
(0,129)
(0,213)
(0,167)
Debts
0,021
0,084**
0,051**
(0,016)
(0,039)
(0,025)
Law
-2,257***
-0,867*
(0,846)
(0,472)
Corruption
0,701
(0,480)
0,090
(0,236)
Bank_zscore
-0,094**
(0,048)
Insur_deposit
0,923
(0,706)
Insurance
0,185
(0,409)
Real estate
-0,278
(0,540)
Non-financial firms
-1,220*
(0,626)
Bakobis
-1,053**
(0,519)
Losses/exchange
2,734*
(1,560)
Losses /loan
0,838
(0,974)
Concentration
0,010
(0,018)
Nb of domestic applications
-0,141
(0,149)
Nb of foreign applications
0,416*
(0,221)
Losses /share
3,102*
(1,645)
Constant
-0,644
-1,626
2,591
(0,740)
(3,308)
(2,347)
Observations
78
59
78

Standard errors in parentheses.
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

5.1. The Regulatory Variables

Bank risk as measured by the Z-score is often used to also measure the stability of the banking system (Lee and Hsieh, 2013). The Z-score is the only risk measure. Our results showed that the coefficient of this variable was significantly negative. Confirming this idea, we could say that the more bank risk increased, the more bank crises were expected. Thus, bank instability had a significant impact on banking crises. Our estimates showed that there was no clear correlation between concentration levels and the crisis. Concentration of the five major banks reduced banking competition, thereby having a positive effect on bank stability.
Our findings were consistent with those of Beck et al. (2006) which examined the impact of the national concentration of banks, regulation of banks and national institutions on the probability of a country suffering from systemic banking crises. They used data on the period between 1980 and 1997 for 69 countries and found that crises were less likely in economies with more concentrated banking systems. The deposit insurance variable had a significantly positive coefficient.

Our results showed that the presence of an explicit deposit insurance system greatly increased the probability of problems in the banking sector alone. The loss of unrealized securities presented a positive sign. Restricting banking activities means restricting banks' activities on the risky securities they may hold. Limitation of risk enterprises may also reduce financial losses in view of the opacity of bank assets. However, the results of Barth et al. (2004) indicated the opposite: the restriction of banking activities was negatively linked to the stability of banks and increased the probability of a banking crisis.

The coefficient of the variable measuring the Loss of Exchange was significantly positive. It seemed that an imbalance in the stock of exchange favored the occurrence of a banking crisis. In addition, the variable measuring the number of foreign applications for a bank license refused affected positively and significantly the appearance of banking crises. This showed that their banking system was not open internationally. A country that liberalizes its economy must work with international software and standards and follow international software so that it can work with banks around the world.

Several works found that the increase of restrictions on stock markets, underwriting insurance, the holding of non-financial corporations by banks or participation in real estate transactions, reduced bank risk taking. We did not find any support for this idea. On the contrary, we found that the restriction on banks' ability to hold and control non-financial businesses increased bank fragility. At the same time, banks that diversified, expanded their revenue streams and became more resilient to shocks had a positive impact on the stability of the banking system.

According to our results, many countries have allowed free cross-ownership of shares between banks and non-financial enterprises. As a result, the regulation on the extent to which a bank can hold shares in a non-financial corporation has affected a bank’s ability to diversify its sources of income.

6. CONCLUSION

Since the early 1980s, systemic banking problems have emerged on several occasions around the world; hence there is a need to understand the links between the fragile banking sector and the economy. Numerous case studies indicated that while experiences varied considerably from country to country and over time, there may have been factors common to all banking crises. In this work we have identified some of these commonalities by estimating a logit model for a large number of countries.

Our results showed that the macroeconomic environment played a key role in banking crises, in particular, if this environment was characterized by: low GDP growth; an increase in credit to the private sector, significant inflation, increased credit and large doubtful accounts. All these indicators seem to have triggered the emergence of banking crises. In this regard, the variables of regulation in the form of: deposit insurance, regulation of the acquisition of banks to non-financial enterprises, exchange loss, loan loss, and the loss of equities were triggers of bank crises.

Moreover, all these factors along with institutional factors in terms of non-compliance with the law have contributed to the vulnerability of banks in emerging countries. It is not necessarily a sign of an inefficient banking system because the role of banks as financial intermediaries implied a certain risk taking. However, banks could have covered some of the credit risk due to fluctuations in the domestic economy by lending abroad.

The results also showed that the restrictions on insurance, the financial market and the real estate sector were unrelated to the outbreak of banking crises contrary to the results of Barth et al. (2004;2008). This suggested that good regulation leads to banking stability. We concluded that diversifying banks could broaden their revenue streams and become more resilient to shocks. This would have a positive impact on the stability of the banking system.

In conclusion, the results of our present work were interesting and could be complemented by the study of American banks following the subprime crisis. We could further discuss the idea of supervision through an evaluation of the effectiveness of control mechanisms of the policy of American banking supervision. From an empirical perspective, we could look at building an effective risk management system that complied with international prudential standards.

Funding: This study received no specific financial support.   
Competing Interests: The author declares that there are no conflicts of interests regarding the publication of this paper.

REFERENCES

Abbas, F., A. Masood and A. Sakhawat, 2017. What determine remittances to Pakistan? The role of macroeconomic, political and financial factors. Journal of Policy Modeling, 39(3): 519-531.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2017.03.006.

Allen, F., E. Carletti and A. Leonello, 2011. Deposit insurance and risk taking. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 27(3): 464-478.

Ambrogio, C.-B., F.E. Martin and G. Thwaites, 2019. Foreign booms, domestic busts: The global dimension of banking crises. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 37: 58-74.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2018.07.001.

Ang, J.B. and W.J. McKibbin, 2007. Financial liberalization, financial sector development and growth: Evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Development Economics, 84(1): 215-233.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.11.006.

Anginer, D., A. Demirguc-Kunt and M. Zhu, 2014. How does competition affect bank systemic risk? Journal of Financial Intermediation, 23(1): 1-26.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2013.11.001.

Angkinand, A.P., W. Sawangngoenyuang and C. Wihlborg, 2010. Financial liberalization and banking crises: A cross-country analysis. International Review of Finance, 10(2): 263-292.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2443.2010.01114.x.

Barth, J.R., G. Caprio and R. Levine, 2004. Bank supervision and regulation: What works best. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(2): 205-248.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2003.06.002.

Barth, J., G. Caprio and R. Levine, 2008. Bank regulations are changing for bandter or worse ? Comparative Economic Studies, 50(4): 537-563.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1057/ces.2008.33.

Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt and R. Levine, 2006. Bank concentration, competition, and crises: First results. Journal of Banking & finance, 30(5): 1581-1603.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2005.05.010.

Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt and V. Maksimovic, 2008. Financing patterns around the world: Are small firms different? Journal of Financial Economics, 89(3): 467-487.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.10.005.

Boyd, J.H. and D.G. Nicolo, 2005. The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. The Journal of Finance, 60(3): 1329-1343.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00763.x.

Calvo, G., 1996. Capital flows and macroeconomic management: Tequila lessons. International Journal of Finance and Economics, 1(3): 207-223.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-1158(199607)1:3<207::aid-ijfe21>3.0.co;2-3.

Cubillas, E. and F. González, 2014. Financial liberalization and bank risk-taking: International evidence. Journal of Financial Stability, 11: 32-48.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2013.11.001.

Cubillas, E. and N. Suárez, 2018. Bank market power and lending during the global financial crisis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 89(C): 1-22.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.08.003.

Demirguc-Kunt, A. and H. Huizinga, 1999. Determinants of commercial bank interest margins and profitability: Some international evidence. World Bank Economic Review, 13(2): 379-408.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/13.2.379.

Egan, M., A. Horta and G. Matvos, 2017. Deposit compandition and financial fragility: Evidence from the US Banking sector. American Economic Review, 107(1): 169-216.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150342.

Gnangnon, S.K., 2018. Multilateral trade liberalization and economic growth. Journal of Economic Integration, 33(2): 1261-1301.Available at: https://doi.org/10.11130/jei.2018.33.2.1261.

Hellmann, T.F., K.C. Murdock and J.E. Stiglitz, 2000. Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: Are capital requirements enough? American Economic Review, 90(1): 147-165.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.1.147.

Joyce, J.P., 2011. Financial globalization and banking crises in emerging markets. Open Economies Review, 22(5): 875-895.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9179-8.

Kane, E.J., 1986. Appearance and reality in deposit insurance: The case for reform. Journal of Banking and Finance, 10(2): 175-188.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/0378-4266(86)90003-8.

Keeley, M.C., 1990. Deposit insurance, risk, and markand power in banking. The American Economic Review, 80(5): 1183-1200.

Khan, H.H., R.B. Ahmad and C.S. Gee, 2016. Bank competition and monetary policy transmission through the bank lending channel: Evidence from ASEAN. International Review of Economics & Finance, 44: 19-39.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2016.03.003.

Klapper, L. and I. Love, 2004. Corporate governance, investor protection, and performance in emerging markands. Journal of Corporate Finance, 10(5): 703-723.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/s0929-1199(03)00046-4.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R. Vishny, 2000. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2): 3-27.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, 1997. Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, 52(3): 1131-1150.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb02727.x.

La Porta, R., D.S.F. Lopez, A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny, 1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6): 1113-1155.

Laeven, L. and F. Valencia, 2013. The real effects of financial sector interventions during crises. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45(1): 147-177.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2012.00565.x.

Lee, C.-C. and M.-F. Hsieh, 2013. The impact of bank capital on profitability and risk in Asian banking. Journal of International Money and Finance, 32(1): 251-281.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.04.013.

Onder, Z. and S. Ozyilidirim, 2019. Foreign banks and short-term macroeconomic fluctuations: Do financial development and regions matter? Economic Systemics, 43(1): 63-76.

Park, J., 2012. Corruption, soundness of the banking sector, and economic growth: A cross-country study. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31(5): 907-929.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2011.07.007.

Rachdi, H., A. Hakimi and H. Hamdi, 2018. Liberalization, crisis and growth in MENA region: Do institutions matter? Journal of Policy Modeling, 40(4): 810-826.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2018.05.001.

Rancière, R. and A. Tornell, 2016. Financial liberalization, debt mismatch, allocative efficiency, and growth. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 8(2): 1-44.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20130190.

Repullo, R., 2004. Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13(2): 156-182.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2003.08.005.

Roy, A.D., 1952. Safandy first and the holding of assands. Econometrica, 20(3): 431- 439.

Schaeck, K., M. Cihak and S. Wolfe, 2009. Are competitive banking systems more stable? Journal of Money, Credit and banking, 41(4): 711-734.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00228.x.

Tanna, S., Y. Luo and G. De Vita, 2017. What is the net effect of financial liberalization on bank productivity? A decomposition analysis of bank total factor productivity growth. Journal of Financial Stability, 30: 67-78.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2017.04.003.

Wu, J., M. Chen, B. Jeon and R. Wang, 2017. Does foreign bank penetration affect the risk of domestic banks? Evidence from emerging economies. Journal of Financial Stability, 31(C): 45-61.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2017.06.004.

Zhang, D., J. Cai, D.G. Dickinson and A.M. Kutan, 2016. Non-performing loans, moral hazard and regulation of the Chinese commercial banking system. Journal of Banking & Finance, 63: 48-60.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2015.11.010.

APPENDIX

Table-A1. List of emerging countries.

Emerging countries
Argentine
Guyana
Peru
Aruba
Honduras
Philippines
Bangladesh
Hongray
Poland
Belarus
India
Puerto Rico
Bhutan
Indonesia
Qatar
Bolivia
Israel
Romania
Botswana
Jamaica
Russia
Brazil
Jordan
Rwanda
British Virgin Islands
Kenya
St Kitts
Burundi
Korea
Samoa
Cambodia
Kuwait
Saudi Arabia
Chile
Latvia
Seychelles
China
Lebanon
Singapore
Croatia
Lesotho
Solomon Islands
Czech Republic
Lithuania
South Africa
Egypt
Macau
Sri Lanka
El Salvador
Macedonia
Tajikistan
Estonia
Malawi
Thailand
Gambia
Malaysia
Tonga
Ghana
Maldives
Trinidad and Tobago
Guatemala
Malta
Turkey
Guernsey
Mauritius
Turks and Caicos
Népal
Mexico
Vanuatu
Nigeria
Moldova
Venezuela
Oman
Maroco
Vietnam
Panama
Namibia
Zambia

Source: Barth et al. (2004).

Views and opinions expressed in this article are the views and opinions of the author(s), Asian Economic and Financial Review shall not be responsible or answerable for any loss, damage or liability etc. caused in relation to/arising out of the use of the content.


Footnotes:

1.Banking competition erodes the value of bankers' insurance and reduces their incentives to act cautiously.

2. Return on assets plus the capital to assets ratio, divided by the standard deviation of the return on assets.