THE IMPACT OF UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY TOOLS ON INFLATION RATES IN THE USA
1Department of Business Administration, Jouf University, KSA.
2,3 Department of Economics, University of Adrar, Algeria.
ABSTRACT
This study analyzed the impact of unconventional monetary policy tools on the expected inflation rates that global central banks targeted as a solution for the liquidity trap that many economies fell into during the 2008 financial crisis. The US economy was adopted as a case study for the period 2003 – 2018 with quarterly time series. The study model was based on credit variables (cr), actual federal interest rates (fir), and the monetary mass (M2), as independent variables and their effect on expected inflation rates as a dependent variable using Vector Auto Regression (VAR). The study found that the impact of credit volume changes on expected inflation rates was insignificant. This can be attributed to unconventional monetary policy tools, especially credit facilitation programs, since they aimed at stabilizing financial markets rather than stimulating higher inflation expectations. The zero-interest-rate policy adopted by the US Federal Reserve as of December 2008 contributed to boosting the expected inflation rates as indicated by the results of the study. The parameters were significant, and the relationship was inverse during the second lag interval. Theoretically, this was expected, according to Paul Krugman's model.
Keywords: Unconventional monetary policy tools, Expected inflation rates, USA economy, Vector auto regression (VAR), Credit, Volume of money, Current federal interest rate.
JEL Classification: E31, E42.
ARTICLE HISTORY: Received: 25 February 2020, Revised: 8 April 2020, Accepted: 11 May 2020, Published: 5 June 2020
Contribution/ Originality: This study contributes to the existing literature for using the VAR model to analyze the impact of unconventional monetary policy tools on the expected inflation rates in the USA. It was measured with three tools: the volume of credit, rates of interest, and the monetary base. The paper revealed that there is a robust and statistically significant negative effect of rates of interest on expected inflation rates.
The crisis of the 2007 summer began in the United States in the market of mortgage securities, more specifically in subprime mortgages. These are mortgages granted to American households that do not meet the conditions for subscribing to a conventional mortgage. Since a subprime mortgage is a monetary tool, the Federal Reserve does not have the ability to directly set mortgage rates; it does create the monetary policies that indirectly affect these rates. The influence of the Federal Reserve can be seen in how its actions affect the price of credit, which is then reflected in the mortgage rates that lenders offer prospective borrowers. These loans, given to the most risky clients, have the particularity of being, generally, at variable rates and backed by the value of the real estate of the borrower (Bricongne, Lapègue, & Monso, 2009).
The development of this form of monetary policy tools has been favored by a relatively stable macroeconomic environment (low inflation, strong), a sustained rise in real estate prices and low-interest rates in the United States. In this environment of very low interest rates, agents have invested in risk-rewarding securities to increase their returns (Altunbas, Gambacorta, & Marques-Ibanez, 2014). This led to the underestimation of risk by financial institutions, rating agencies, regulators, and investors. This was accelerated by the birth of a class of non-bank real estate brokers who were not subject to the same regulations as banks. These agents, called structured investment vehicles, acted like banks borrowing on a very short-term basis, and financing highly structured products. At the same time, there has been an increase in the securitization of mortgages or the proceeds of these securities (Brennan, Hein, & Poon, 2009).
The 2007 crisis began with the difficulty faced by US households in repaying their mortgage loans. With variable-rate being sub primes, the increase in the US rate of interest from 1% (in 2004) to 5.25% (in 2006) increased the financial expenses of borrowers. At the same time, the real estate bubble that had been going on since the 1980s erupted as early as February 2007 (Kanga, 2017).
The American model is considered as one of the most important successful experiments in applying unconventional monetary policy tools, due to the approach of the Euro indicators, which also defined a variation in the results achieved by member states due to the lack of economic homogeneity between them and different financing structure and the degree of presence of financial intermediation in the markets etc. (Atsushi & Barbara, 2018). However, in terms of indicators, inflation rates in the Euro area are still meager after almost ten years of actual application of unconventional monetary policy tools (Gambacorta, Hofmann, & Peersman, 2014). As for the Japanese experience, it was the first to implement unconventional monetary policy tools through the implementation of quantitative easing programs during the period 2001-2006, but the weak results and repercussions of the recent financial crisis forced the Japanese Central Bank to re-apply new packages of unconventional monetary policy tools to developing countries (Morgan, 2009).
Krugman's model is however speculated as an effective tool to help in the exit of the economy from the liquidity trap. Consequently, the central bank can reduce nominal long-term interest rates in order to influence real long-term interest rates. This can also influence economic agents’ expectations, in particular, the expected inflation rate, which encourages immediate consumption and thus can potentially stimulate economic growth (Engen, Thomas, & David, 2015; Krugman, 2000). In general, it can also lead to achieving the usual objective of monetary policy in the light of financial crises and the state of the liquidity trap. This is, of course, delivered by applying an integrated blend and a mixture of unconventional monetary tools embodied in quantitative easing; credit facilitation, negative and zero interest rates; advance guidance (conditional or unconditional Central Bank announcements).
From the above, we raise the question of how unconventional monetary policy tools can impact the expected inflation rates in the US for the period 2003-2018. This study analyzed the impact of unconventional monetary policy tools on the expected inflation rates in the USA in the real estate sector. The study used three measuring tools: the volume of credit, rates of interest, and the monetary base. The findings revealed that there is a robust and statistically significant negative effect of rates of interest on expected inflation rates.
Literature shows that heterogeneity in the Eurozone is at the origin of asymmetry in the transmission of interest rate policy (Barigozzi, Conti, & Luciani, 2014; Ehrmann, Gambacorta, Martinez-Pagés, Sevestre, & Worms, 2003; Frontmatter, 2003). In particular, the structure of the banking sector plays a critical role in the transmission of monetary policy in the Eurozone (Mojon, 2000). For example, Germany and Italy would be more exposed to financial shock than Finland, France, and Spain due to a high concentration of banks and the size of the equity market as a substitute for bank loans (Semenescu-Badarau & Levieuge, 2010), the market power of banks (Berger, 1995; Sorensen & Werner, 2006) and banking competition (Corvoisier & Gropp, 2002; Sander & Kleimeier, 2004).
There are various factors that influence the transmission of bank interest rates. Bank rates adjust more quickly in countries with relatively intense banking competition or where banks have weak market power. The rate adjustment is also slow where banks are highly liquid, highly capitalized, and more exposed to interest risk (Sorensen & Werner, 2006). At the same time, credit risk accelerates the transmission of monetary policy (Valverde & Fernández, 2007). Finally, cyclical factors (growth, housing prices, and credit growth) also tend to slow the adjustment of bank rates (Sorensen & Werner, 2006).
The Federal Reserve has been criticized for not meeting its goals of greater stability and low inflation (Selgin, Lastrapes, & White, 2012).This has led to a number of proposed changes including advocacy of different policy rules (Salter, 2014).
Milton Friedman concluded that governments play a major role in monetary system (Friedman & Schwartz, 1986). He was critical of the Federal Reserve due to its poor performance and felt it should be abolished. Friedman believed that the Federal Reserve System should ultimately be replaced with a computer program. He favored a system that would automatically buy and sell securities in response to changes in the money supply (Friedman, 1996). This proposal is known as Friedman's k-percent rule (Salter, 2014).
Others have proposed NGDP targeting as an alternative rule to guide and improve central bank policy. Prominent supporters include Scott Sumner, David Beckworth, and Tyler Cowen (Cord & Hammond, 2016).
Some economists, such as Taylor (2010) have asserted that the Federal Reserve (Fed) was responsible, at least partially, for the United States housing bubble which occurred prior to the 2007 recession. They claim that the Fed kept interest rates too low following the 2001 recession (Labonte & Makinen, 2005). The housing bubble then led to the credit crunch. Then-Chairman Alan Greenspan disputes this interpretation. He points out that the Fed’s control over the long-term interest rates (to which critics refer) is only indirect. The Fed did raise the short-term interest rate over which it has control (i.e., the federal funds rate), but the long-term interest rate (which usually follows the former) did not increase (Labonte & Makinen, 2005).
Many central banks implemented unconventional policies during the 2008 financial crisis, most notably the Federal Reserve, as they initially sought to buy alternative assets to alleviate financial market distress, but their goals soon expanded to include achieving inflation targets for stimulating the real economy (Dell’Ariccia, Rabanal, & Sandri, 2018). The nature of central bank financial systems strongly influenced unconventional monetary policy methods, with the European Central Bank and Bank of Japan focused on direct lending to banks. In contrast, the Federal Reserve System and the Bank of England bought bonds to expand their monetary bases. Hence, these differences in the application of monetary policy were traditional to inter-central banks that made it difficult to generalize about their effects (Bibow, 2018).
The application of unconventional monetary policy tools emerged prominently after the 2008 global financial crisis. This affected the global financial markets and the global economy in general, including the United States of America, the Eurozone, and various emerging economies (Potter & Smets, 2019; Svensson, 2015). To contain this crisis, where the traditional monetary policy tools were used by the global central banks, economic decision-makers were prompted to urgently adopt new exceptional tools not mentioned in previous economic thinking theories. All these advantages, have increased the significance made for unconventional monetary policy tools (Engen et al., 2015).
This study addresses several issues. First is the increase in the US interest rate from 1% (in 2004) to 5.25% (in 2006) that increased the financial expenses of borrowers. Second, this study examines the impact of the real-estate bubble, which had been going on since the 1980s, but burst as early as February 2007. In order to address to such issues, this study aimed at answering the following question: How do the unconventional monetary policy tools affect inflation rates in the USA during the period 2003-2018?
We chose a combination of variables that reflect the unconventional monetary policy programs in the United States, which are indicative of all the unconventional monetary changes made by the Federal Reserve System (The Fed) in its monetary policy. These changes were brought to contain the financial crisis and exit the liquidity trap. The issues of financial crisis and the US monetary policy have been discussed in several previous studies but very few have dealt with the effects of unconventional monetary policy tools on a range of economic variables using different statistical models. Moreover, no other study has referred to theoretical and scientific aspects of these issues. Hence, in order to fill this research gap, this study was designed.
The correlation analysis in this study will enable to find whether the expected inflation rates are correlated with the change in the independent variables in terms of volume of credit, federal interest rates, and money supply in the United States during the study period.
To study the impact of unconventional monetary policy tools on inflation rates during the period 2003 to 2018 in the USA, the quarterly data for all variables based on nominal values compounded were collected from the Federal Reserve Bank:
In this study, the data were analyzed by vector autoregressive (VAR) model. The VAR (p) model without trend with k stationary endogenous variable at the level or integrated of order one, I(0) is as follows:
The test results are illustrated in Table 1.
First model: without either an interceptor or a trend; Second model: with an intercept; Third model: with an intercept and a general trend.
Table-1. Results of ADF for time series.
* Significant at the level of 5% according to the tabular values of MacKinnon (1996).
** Significant at the level of 1% according to the tabular values of MacKinnon (1996).
Table 1 illustrates the EViews output showing:
Figure 1 is a graphic representation of the study variables after the first differences were made:
Figure-1. Graphical curve showing the variables of the study model variables using stationary series.
Source: EViews output.
To ensure the stationarity of the model, as shown in Figure 2, we made sure that all the roots were located within the unit circle, which meant that the model did not suffer from heteroskedasticity.
Figure-2. The unit circle of the model of the impact of unconventional monetary policy changes on expected inflation rates in the USA during the period 2003-2017.
Source: EViews output.
There were several statistical criteria for determining the lag intervals appropriate for estimating the study model, as shown in the Table 2. It also summarizes the estimation results of the criteria values for determining the length of the lag time.
Table-2. Optimal lag selection
Lag |
LogL |
LR |
FPE |
AIC |
SC |
HQ |
0 |
170.80 |
NA |
1.30 |
-6.80 |
-6.65 |
-6.74 |
1 |
298.30 |
228.98 |
1.37 |
-11.35 |
-10.58 |
-11.06 |
2 |
351.03 |
86.09* |
3.11 |
-12.85 |
-11.46* |
-12.33* |
3 |
368.92 |
26.27 |
2.98* |
-12.93 |
-10.92 |
-12.17 |
4 |
381.35 |
16.24 |
3.70 |
-12.79 |
-10.16 |
-11.79 |
5 |
390.03 |
9.914 |
5.60 |
-12.49 |
-9.24 |
-11.26 |
* indicates lag order selected by the criterion, LR: sequentially modified LR test statistic (each test at 5% level), FPE: Final prediction error, AIC: Akaike information criterion, SC: Schwarz information criterion, HQ: Hannan-Quinn information criterion.
According to the Schwarz information (SC) criterion, the minimum time lag length of the VAR model in the level was the second period (t+2).
Since all the endogenous variables of this research were integrated of order one, I(1) and not cointegrated, then the estimated VAR model was:
DLINF = - 0.196*DLINF (-1) - 0.096*DLINF (-2) - 1.622*LCR1(-1) + 1.54*LCR1(-2) + 0.58*DLFIR (-1) - 0.34*DLFIR (-2) + 9.678*DLM2(-1) - 11.033*DLM2(-2) + 0.003.
Where the value of all coefficients is derived as summarized in Table 3.
Table-3. Vector auto-regression estimates.
Source: Prepared by the researchers based on Eviews outputs.
**The coefficient significance is at 5 % , which means that (=1.67).As summarized in Table 3, the coefficient values of the variable Dlfir (-2) was slowed for two periods, which carried a positive and significant 5%, indicating that there was a direct relationship between the Fed interest rates and the inflation rate. It can be said that the elasticity of the inflation rate for changes in federal interest rates was estimated at (0.58). The significance of the coefficient of the volume of money was slowed for one period Dlm2 (-1), and it carried a positive signal indicating that there was a direct relationship between the inflation rate and the size of the monetary value, so that the elasticity of the inflation rate for changes in the volume of money was estimated at about (9.67). ). When the results showed the non-significance of credit size, then there was no effect of the latter on the rate of inflation. The summary of these statistics are reported in Appendix 1.
Table 4 , summarizes the R-squared (R2) coefficient (R2 = .0.7420) which indicates that there is a high explanatory power of the model. The changes in the explanatory variables are included in the model and explained as 74.20% of the fluctuations in the inflation rate. This suggests that expected inflation rates are strongly correlated with the change in the independent variables in terms of volume of credit, federal interest rates, and money supply in the United States during the study period. This is explained by the coefficient of determination R2 = 74.20% and the existence of a significant interpretative ability of the independent variables, which estimate the corrected coefficient of determination at 69.40% in attempting to interpret the evolution of expected inflation rates. The other parts are explained by other variables that do not exist in the model.
Table-4. Results of model estimates of inflation rates through the volume of credit, federal interest rates, and money supply.
R-Squared |
74.20 % |
Adj R-squared |
69.40% |
S.E. equation |
0.24 |
F-statistic |
15.45 |
Log-likelihood |
4.20 |
Akaike AIC |
0.18 |
Schwarz SC |
0.52 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019
As for the calculated Fischer value (F_stat = 15.45), it was higher than the tabular value (F_tab=1.67) at the 5% level of significance, and it indicated the validity of the estimated model as a whole.
The study results showed the high value of Fischer's statistic model as follows: Fc = 15.45 >, Ft = 2.76, which was higher than Fischer's statistic tabulated value of the model. After conducting a set of tests on the study, which were mentioned earlier, it was stated that the model was acceptable, both generally and statistically.
A set of statistical diagnostic tests Jarque-Bera Test, Serial Correlation LM Test and White heteroskedasticity test were conducted on the model to ensure its adequacy. In other words, it was important to determine whether the model was free of standard problems and that it must not suffer from any standard problems so that the estimation results can be analyzed. The detailed findings of these tests are available in Appendix 2 and 3.
Table 5 summarizes the results of these tests
Table-5. The results of tests of standard problems.
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019
Based on this, two hypotheses were framed:
Serial Correlation LM Test was conducted to find out whether there was autocorrelation or not. Since the probabilities of the model are bigger at (0.05 < 0.06 ) when (P=2) and (0.05 < 0.35) when (P=3); therefore, we reject the hypothesis H0, which means that there is no autocorrelation.
Similarly, White heteroskedasticity test (Breusch–Pagan test was conducted to examine the heteroskedasticity
Because the probability of the model was greater at 5% (pro=0.11 >0.05), (pro = 0.30 >0.05). Therefore, we accept the hypothesis H1, which means that there is homoscedasticity.
The Jarque-Bera Testi was conducted to make sure that the residues follow a normal distribution. Since the probability of testing was 0.00001, which is smaller than the 5% level of significance, it was proved that the residues followed a normal distribution.
To measure the multicollinearity between interpretive variables of the second model, we used the Klein Test, where R2 calculated using this model was compared with the correlation coefficients of independent variables (volume of credit, federal interest rates, and volume of the money supply). Table 6 presents the matrix of multi-collinearity among independent variables:
Table-6. Matrix of multi-collinearity among independent variables (X1 ).
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019.
Through this matrix we found that the coefficient of determination R2 = 74.20% was higher than these coefficients, and therefore there was no multi-collinearity (xi). As a final note, the model can be said to be devoid of standard problems and can be economically analyzed.
The analysis of the variance between the study variables and their impact on each other was determined by determining the amount of variance in the prediction for each variable, which was due to the prediction error in the same variable and the rest of the other variables. Table 7 illustrates the analysis of variance of expected inflation rates model:
Table-7. Analysis of variance of the study model during ten time periods
Variance Decomposition of DLINF |
|||||
Period |
S.E |
DLINF |
LCR1 |
DLFIR |
DLM2 |
1 |
0.245 |
100.000 |
0.000 |
0.000 |
0.000 |
2 |
0.383 |
41.246 |
14.305 |
39.760 |
4.687 |
3 |
0.474 |
32.861 |
18.227 |
43.464 |
5.446 |
4 |
0.477 |
32.629 |
18.159 |
42.968 |
6.242 |
5 |
0.479 |
32.452 |
17.999 |
43.031 |
6.516 |
6 |
0.480 |
32.424 |
18.116 |
42.960 |
6.499 |
7 |
0.480 |
32.359 |
18.208 |
42.902 |
6.529 |
8 |
0.480 |
32.349 |
18.219 |
42.903 |
6.527 |
9 |
0.480 |
32.336 |
18.256 |
42.883 |
6.524 |
10 |
0.480 |
32.323 |
18.283 |
42.867 |
6.525 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019
The results of the analysis of the variance components of the expected inflation rates model showed that 100% of the forecast rate in the variance of inflation rates in the first period was attributed to the same variable. In contrast, in the second period, 41.24% of the forecast rate was due to the same variable. Also, the variable of the volume of credit in the non-financial private sector was at 14.30%, the federal interest rate variable was at 39.76%, and the variable of the money supply was at 4.68%. This fluctuation in the rates continued until the last period, i.e., the tenth period to become 32.32% for the same variable, 18.28% for the variable of the volume of credit, 42.86% for interest rates and 6 .52% of the money supply variable. Based on this analysis, it was noted that the proportion of the contribution of the independent variables of the model in explaining the evolution of expected inflation rates was acceptable, particularly for the short, medium and long-term federal interest rate variables, which demonstrated the significant impact of changes in the volume of credit to the non-financial private sector, federal interest rates, and money supply. They together were considered as strong indicators of changes in expected inflation rates.
Among the statistical methods used to illustrate the behavior of the model, we relied on analyzing the impulses of the response of expected inflation rates when positive shocks occur on the level of independent variables such as the dependent variable itself during ten periods and one standard deviation.
Table 8 presents the impulse response estimate of the expected inflation rates:
Table-8. The results of the impulse response estimate of the expected inflation rates
Period |
DLINF |
LCR1 |
DLFIR |
DLM2 |
1 |
0.245 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0.265 |
0.145 |
0.241 |
0.083 |
3 |
0.150 |
0.003 |
0.043 |
0.009 |
4 |
0.168 |
-0.014 |
0.040 |
-0.034 |
5 |
0.186 |
-0.008 |
0.073 |
-0.006 |
6 |
0.175 |
-0.027 |
0.064 |
-0.006 |
7 |
0.174 |
-0.044 |
0.056 |
-0.016 |
8 |
0.177 |
-0.051 |
0.062 |
-0.016 |
9 |
0.174 |
-0.061 |
0.061 |
-0.017 |
10 |
0.173 |
-0.070 |
0.059 |
-0.020 |
Cholesky Ordering: DLINF LCR1 DLFIR DLM2 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019
The above table shows that a shock in the expected inflation rates Dlinf in the first period leads to a positive shock in the same variable in the first period by 0.24% and 0.26% in the second period. These are the highest and largest shock recorded during the study period, the impact of shocks positively continues throughout the remaining periods. As for the volume of credit LCr1, a shock of one standard deviation leads to a positive shock in the expected inflation rates by 0.145%, which was the biggest shock recorded in the second period. As of the fourth period, negative responses were recorded to the last period when the biggest negative shock in inflation rates was at (-0.07%).
However, when a shock in the federal interest rates Dlfir takes place with one standard deviation, this led to positive shocks in the expected inflation rates during the ten periods, where the most extensive recorded shock in the second period was 0.24. Finally, when there was a shock in the volume of money supply Dlm2 with one standard deviation, this led to the rotation of the impact on inflation rates up and down positively and negatively, where the largest positive shock recorded in the second period was at 0.08% and the biggest negative shock recorded in the fourth period was at (- 0.034%). After this period all the shocks were adverse in the very last period.
When testing the selection of the appropriate lag interval to estimate the model, we found that it was the second lag interval (t + 2). Thus, we looked at the analysis of the relationships between inflation rates and independent variables in general in the first and second lag intervals. But in the final analysis of the results obtained from the second model, the results of the relationships between the variables relied on those of the second lag interval.
We analyzed the impact of independent variables, which serve as indicators of unconventional monetary policy on the expected inflation rates. According to the outputs of the standard model, the results revealed an inverse relationship in the first lag interval and a direct relationship in the second interval.
The results of the study indicated that the changes in the volume of credit in the first and second lag intervals were insignificant and also indicate an inverse and direct relationship between the changes in the volume of credit of the non-financial private sector and the expected inflation rates in the USA as when the credit volume increases by 1% (t+1), this leads to a decline in the expected inflation rates by -1.622% in the interval (t + 1), and rates rose by 1.54% in the second lag interval (t + 2).
This can be interpreted in terms of the elasticity and degree of response to the expected inflation rates to the changes in the volume of credit is big and very statistically acceptable. The increase in the volume of credit in the non-financial sector negatively impacted inflation expectations in the first lag interval, where the increase in credit volume indicated the increase in the volume of financing for the non-financial private sector and thus contributed to the increase in aggregate supply and production rather than the total demand. Thus, this stimulated a rise in the expected inflation rates. Therefore, the overall supply gap contributed to lower expected inflation rates.
In the second lag interval, the relationship between two variables was positive, where the impact of credit volume was positive to inflation expectations, which is theoretically expected. Bank loans to the private sector are one of the main pillars to increase consumption rates and overall demand in general, and thus stimulate future prices to rise. Also, providing the necessary financing for economic activity has a positive impact on stimulating the general levels of prices.
The results of the applied study revealed a direct relationship in the first lag interval, whereas there was an inverse relationship in the second lag interval as follows:
The results of the study indicated significant changes in interest rates in the first (t + 1) and second (t + 2) lag intervals at the level of 1%. It was noted that the parameters of federal interest rates were highly significant. The results referred to a direct relationship between the changes in federal interest rates and expected inflation rates in the United States during the first lag interval, whereas an inverse relationship existed in the second lag interval. When interest rates rose by 1% (t), this led to increasing inflation rates by 0.58% (t + 1), and (0.34%) in (t + 2). It was noted that through the elasticity of response between the two variables, the effect of changes in interest rates contributed to stimulating an increase in expected inflation rates. When adopting unconventional monetary policy, the Federal Reserve applied the federal interest rates very close to zero (in addition to the policy of pre-orientation) to affect the long-term nominal interest rates to influence expectations and reassuring financial markets in light of the financial crisis and to find a way out of the liquidity trap that hit the US economy. This affected the borrowing costs and stimulated the volume of consumption and necessarily caused an increase in the expected inflation rates.
The inverse relationship between changes in interest rates and expected inflation rates was explained by the phenomenon of monetary hoarding among individuals and the adverse effect of quantitative easing and credit facilitation programs on inflation expectations. Despite the increase in the money supply through these programs, individuals do not prefer consumption. Instead, they prefer monetary hoarding due to the degree of risk and uncertainty that adversely affects the development of aggregate demand. This is along with the presence of short-term nominal interest rates at levels close to zero with a cash shock. Accordingly, current prices are higher than expected, causing a recession in prices. In this case, individuals would prefer consumption when prices are low in the future. So, to stimulate the individuals' immediate use and to fully exploit the economic resources, individuals' income and savings should lose their values, in general. This is achieved by influencing the long-term nominal interest rates applied through an unconventional monetary policy, where nominal interest rates are meager in the long run. This explains why the federal interest rates remain at low levels to stimulate inflation expectations.
The results revealed the existence of a direct relationship in the first lag interval, whereas it was of an inverse nature in the second one. The results of the study showed the significant changes in the money supply in the first and second lag intervals. Therefore, when the volume of money supply increased by 1%, it also led to increase the expected inflation rates by 9.67% in the first lag interval and decrease rates by 11.03% in the second lag interval. Additionally, it was noted that the elasticity or the degree of response of the expected inflation rates to the changes in the money supply was high. This indicated that the hypothesis of the quantum theory of money was achieved, where inflation rates rise when the money supply increases in the first lag interval, whereas it was reversed in the second lag interval during the period of study in the United States of America.
Through the application of both quantitative easing and credit facilitation, monetary shock contributed to the rise in the size of the money supply in the economy and the stability of production volume. This was because the goal of unconventional expansionary monetary policy is to stimulate aggregate demand and not aggregate supply. The stability of the speed of money turnover contributed to increasing expected inflation rates on a big scale in the USA.
The study reached several results, which are summarized as follows:
Funding: This study received no specific financial support. |
Competing Interests: The authors declare that they have no competing interests. |
Acknowledgement: All authors contributed equally to the conception and design of the study. |
Altunbas, Y., Gambacorta, L., & Marques-Ibanez, D. (2014). Does monetary policy affect bank risk-taking? International Journal of Central Banking, 10(1), 95–135.
Atsushi, I., & Barbara, R. (2018). The effects of conventional and unconventional monetary policy: A new approach. Barcelona: Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 1082.
Barigozzi, M., Conti, A. M., & Luciani, M. (2014). Do euro area countries respond asymmetrically to the common monetary policy? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 76(5), 693-714.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/obes.12038.
Berger, A. N. (1995). The profit-structure relationship in banking--tests of market-power and efficient-structure hypotheses. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27(2), 404-431.Available at: https://doi.org/10.2307/2077876.
Bibow, J. (2018). Unconventional monetary policies and central bank profits: Seigniorage as fiscal revenue in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. Levy Economics Institute, Working Papers Series WP No. 916.
Brennan, M. J., Hein, J., & Poon, S.-H. (2009). Tranching and rating. European Financial Management, 15(5), 891-922.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-036x.2009.00515.x.
Bricongne, J.-C., Lapègue, V., & Monso, O. (2009). Subprimes: From the financial crisis to the economic crisis. National Institute of Statistics and Economic Studies, 23-41.
Cord, R., & Hammond, J. D. (2016). Milton Friedman: Contributions to economics and public policy (pp. 246). Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.
Corvoisier, S., & Gropp, R. (2002). Bank concentration and retail interest rates. Journal of Banking & Finance, 26(11), 2155-2189.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/s0378-4266(02)00204-2.
Dell’Ariccia, G., Rabanal, P., & Sandri, D. (2018). Unconventional monetary policies in the Euro Area, Japan, and the United Kingdom. Washington: Hutchins Center Working Paper #48.
Ehrmann, M., Gambacorta, L., Martinez-Pagés, J., Sevestre, P., & Worms, A. (2003). The effects of monetary policy in the euro area. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 19(1), 58-72.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/19.1.58.
Engen, E. M., Thomas, L., & David, R. (2015). The macroeconomic effects of the federal reserve’s unconventional monetary policies. Finance and economics discussion series 2015-005. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve.
Friedman, M. (1996). The counter-revolution in monetary theory. In Explorations in Economic Liberalism (pp. 3-21). London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. J. (1986). Has government any role in money? Journal of Monetary Economics, 17(1), 37-62.Available at: 10.1016/0304-3932(86)90005-x.
Frontmatter. (2003). In I. Angeloni, A. Kashyap, & B. Mojon (Eds.), Monetary policy transmission in the Euro Area: A study by the Eurosystem monetary transmission network. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gambacorta, L., Hofmann, B., & Peersman, G. (2014). The effectiveness of unconventional monetary policy at the zero lower bound: A cross-country analysis. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 46(4), 615-642.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12119.
Kanga, K. D. (2017). Essays on the impact of unconventional monetary policies in the euro area. Orléans: University of Orleans.
Krugman, P. (2000). Thinking about the liquidity trap. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 14(4), 221-237.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1006/jjie.2000.0458.
Labonte, M., & Makinen, G. E. (2005). Federal reserve interest rate changes: 2000-2005. Washington, D.C: Congressional Information Service, Library of Congress.
MacKinnon, J. G. (1996). Numerical distribution functions for unit root and cointegration tests. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(6), 601-618.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-1255(199611)11:6<601::aid-jae417>3.0.co;2-t.
Mojon, B. (2000). Financial structure and the interest rate channel of ECB monetary policy. ECB Working Paper No. 40. European Central Bank.
Morgan, P. (2009). The role and effectiveness of unconventional monetary policy, No. 163. Japan: Asian Development Bank Institute.
Potter, S. M., & Smets, F. (2019). Unconventional monetary policy tools: A cross-country_analysis. Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS) Papers No. 63 Bank for International Settlements. Retrieved from: https://www.bis.org/publ/cgfs63.pdf.
Salter, A. W. (2014). An introduction to monetary policy rules. Retrieved from: http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.669.2842&rep=rep1&type=pdf: Mercatus Center.
Sander, H., & Kleimeier, S. (2004). Convergence in euro-zone retail banking? What interest rate pass-through tells us about monetary policy transmission, competition and integration. Journal of International Money and Finance, 23(3), 461-492.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2004.02.001.
Selgin, G., Lastrapes, W. D., & White, L. H. (2012). Has the Fed been a failure? Journal of Macroeconomics, 34(3), 569-596.Available at: https://doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.02.003.
Semenescu-Badarau, C., & Levieuge, G. (2010). Assessing the potential strength of a bank capital channel in Europe: A principal component analysis. The Review of Finance and Banking, 2(1), 5–16.
Sorensen, C. K., & Werner, T. (2006). Bank interest rate pass-through in the euro area: A cross country comparison. Working Paper Series No. 580. European Central Bank.
Svensson, L. O. (2015). Forward guidance, NBER, RBNZ and IJCB conference. International Journal of Central Banking, 11(S1), 24 - 25.
Taylor, J. B. (2010). The fed and the crisis: A reply to Ben Bernanke. Wall Street Journal, 11, A19.
Valverde, S. C., & Fernández, F. R. (2007). The determinants of bank margins in European banking. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31(7), 2043-2063.Available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.06.017.
Appendix-1. Model estimation table
R-squared |
0.742001 |
0.994282 |
0.205849 |
0.350679 |
Adj. R-squared |
0.694001 |
0.993219 |
0.0581 |
0.229875 |
Sum s q. resids |
2.590434 |
0.00121 |
7.36663 |
0.004995 |
S.E equation |
O.245444 |
0.005306 |
0.413905 |
0.010778 |
F-statistic |
15.4584 |
934.7013 |
1.393234 |
2.902881 |
Log likelihood |
4.200073 |
203.5823 |
-22.97344 |
166.7288 |
Akaike AIC |
0.184613 |
-7.483936 |
1.229748 |
-6.066491 |
Schwarz SC |
0.522328 |
-7.14622 |
1.567463 |
-5.728775 |
Mean dependent |
0.001248 |
0.008058 |
-0.017337 |
-0.005469 |
S.D. dependent |
0.443703 |
0.06443 |
0.426479 |
0.012282 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019
VECM Auto regression Leaniares | |||||
Date: 06/15/2019 Time: 19:23 | |||||
Sample (adjusted) 2003Q4 2016Q3 | |||||
Included observations: 52 after adjustments | |||||
Standard errors in ( )& t-statistics in [] | |||||
DLINF |
LCR1 |
DLFIR |
DLM2 |
||
DLINF(-1) | -0.196595 (0.12505) [-1.57213] |
-0.001699 (0.00270) [-1.62843] |
-0.329471 (0.21088) [-1.56238] |
0.002073 (0.00549) [0.37742] |
|
DLINF(-2) | -0.096415 (0.09776) [-0.98624] |
-0.001329 (0.00211) [-0.62884] |
-0.116136 (0.16486) [-0.70446] |
0.001777 (0.00429) [0.41390] |
|
LCRA(-1) | -1.622037 (3.87906) [-0.41815] |
1.803095 (0.08385) [21.5029] |
-4.317474 (6.54146) [-0.66002] |
0.076374 (0.17034) [0.44836] |
|
LCRA(-2) | 1.547732 (3.93098) [0.39373] |
-0.828266 (0.08498) [-9.74704] |
1.879843 (6.62902) [0.28358] |
-0.123206 (0.17262) [-0.71374] |
|
DLFIR(-1) |
0.580253 (0.10156) [5.71333] |
0.000473 (0.00220) [0.21536] |
-0.084943 (0.17127) [-0.49597] |
0.004202 (0.00446) [0.94215] |
|
DLFIR(-2) | -0.345951 (0.13145) [-2.63188] |
-0.001242 (0.00284) [-0.43709] |
0.189714 (0.22167) [0.85586] |
-0.000219 (0.00577) [-0.03789] |
|
DLM2(-1) | 9.678298 (4.19843) [2.30522] |
0.030096 (0.09076) [0.33161] |
2.206978 (7.08003) [0.31172] |
0.327030 (0.18436) [1.77382] |
Appendix-2. White heteroskedasticity test.
VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests: No Cross Terms (only levels and squares) | |||||
Date: 06/15/2019 Time: 20:48 | |||||
Sample: 2003Q1 2017Q3 | |||||
Included observations: 52 | |||||
Joint test | |||||
Chi-sq | df |
Prob. |
|||
182.0236 | 160 |
0.1121 |
|||
Individual components: | |||||
Dependent | R-squared |
F(16,35) |
Prob. |
Chi-sq(16) |
Prob. |
res1*res1 | O.679016 |
4.627472 |
0.0001 |
35.30881 |
0.0036 |
res2*res2 | 0.343077 |
1.14242 |
0.3577 |
17.84002 |
0.3333 |
res3*res3 | 0.217416 |
0.607727 |
0.856 |
11.30563 |
0.7902 |
res4*res4 | 0.245992 |
0.713663 |
0.7616 |
12.79159 |
0.6879 |
res2*res1 | 0.156309 |
0.405275 |
0.9717 |
8.128082 |
0.945 |
res3*res1 | 0.269972 |
0.796699 |
0.6794 |
13.88256 |
0.6075 |
res3*res2 | 0.286909 |
0.880131 |
0.595 |
14.91927 |
0.5306 |
res4*res1 | 0.410011 |
1.520199 |
0.1476 |
21.3206 |
0.1665 |
res4*res2 | 0.21627 |
0.603641 |
0.8593 |
11.25606 |
0.794 |
res4*res3 | 0.269138 |
0.805543 |
0.6704 |
13.9952 |
0.5991 |
VAR Residual Heteroskedasticity Tests: Includes Cross Terms | |||||
Date: 06/15/2019 Time: 20:52 | |||||
Sample: 2003Q1 2017Q3 | |||||
Included observations: 52 | |||||
Joint test | |||||
Chi-sq | df |
Prob. |
|||
454.2047 | 440 |
0.3099 |
|||
Individual components: | |||||
Dependent | R-squared |
F(44,7) |
Prob. |
Chi-sq(44) |
Prob. |
res1*res1 | 0.975992 |
0.467577 |
0.0075 |
50.7516 |
0.2248 |
res2*res2 | 0.925591 |
1.978973 |
0.1745 |
48.13074 |
0.3093 |
res3*res3 | 0.771401 |
0.536849 |
0.9009 |
40.11288 |
0.6389 |
res4*res4 | 0.866985 |
1.036945 |
0.5313 |
45.08321 |
0.4264 |
res2*res1 | 0.859177 |
0.970633 |
0.576 |
44.67721 |
0.4432 |
res3*res1 | 0.843542 |
0.857737 |
0.6584 |
43.86419 |
0.4774 |
res3*res2 | 0.901442 |
1.455102 |
0.3179 |
45.87501 |
0.3554 |
res4*res1 | 0.898153 |
1.402963 |
0.3386 |
46.70394 |
0.3619 |
res4*res2 | 0.860283 |
0.979574 |
0.5698 |
44.73472 |
0.4408 |
res4*res3 | 0.857742 |
0.959236 |
0.584 |
44.60258 |
0.4463 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019 |
Appendix-3. Jarque-bera test
Component |
Jarque-Bera |
df |
Prob. |
1 |
0.858494 |
2 |
0.651 |
2 |
15.92956 |
2 |
0.0003 |
3 |
44.80168 |
2 |
0 |
4 |
29.45612 |
2 |
0 |
Joint |
91.04586 |
8 |
0 |
Source: EViews 9 Output, 2019.
Views and opinions expressed in this article are the views and opinions of the author(s), Asian Economic and Financial Review shall not be responsible or answerable for any loss, damage or liability etc. caused in relation to/arising out of the use of the content. |